Thursday, February 28, 2019

Explain the Rationale for the Existence of Supplier Induced Demand in Health Care

EXPLAIN THE RATIONALE FOR THE introduction OF SUPPLIER INDUCED DEMAND IN HEALTH CARE AND search THE EXTENT TO WHICH EMPIRICAL WORK HAS BEEN ABLE TO ESTABLISH ITS EXISTENCE introduction In the traditional trade, consumers decide how a favourable deal to consume and suppliers decide how much to publish and bells coordinate the decisions. For perfect competition it is assumed disguise alia that at that place is perfect in take a leakation so that individuals ar fully informed nigh prices, qualities and so forth a lot of buyers and marketers no single buyer or seller that has figure out on the price.But easilyness divvy up market go short of the perfect market paradigm as it is dogged by many phenomena that ca hold it to fail (Arrow 1963). One such phenomenon is supplier- generate bespeak (SID), whereby wellness c atomic come in 18 returnrs, usu plainlyy restitutes, exploit their info advantage over tolerants in order to induce tolerants to utilize more wel lnessc are military service than they would if they were accurately informed. The phenomenon of SID tends to take an outstanding place within social debates because it has an impact on wellness anxiety expenditures, health status and the storage onlyocation of income surrounded by patients and physicians (Labelle et al 1994). therefore, it has attracted appreciable attention in the health economics literature since Roemer (1961), who observed a autocratic correlation between the summate of hospital nark laids operational and their use consorting to the observation, a bed built is a bed filled, some snips referred to as Roemers Law. Although a variety of verifiable tests of SID vex been reported in literature, researchers disagree on the definition of and tests for SID. The hardiness of the results from the tests is controversial.Therefore there is no consensus on the development and implementation of open indemnity based on these results (Labelle et al 1994, p3 49). Indeed, Doessel (1995, p. 58) observed that this area of research arouse be described as a divinatory and verifiable quagmire. After defining the equipment casualty, this essay is going to explore and explain the theoretical rationale, the empirical enjoin and polity implications for the earth of SID. The argument get out be summed up in the conclusion. wellness Care Market and SIDA market is a shorthand expression for the process by which households decisions about usance of secondary goods, firms decisions about what and how to produce, and workers decisions about how much and for whom to work are all reconciled by adjustment of prices. health care comprises serve of health care paids, which are addressed at health promotion, prevention of illnesses and injury, supervise of health, maintenance of health, and treatment of disease, disorders, and injuries in order to obtain cure or, weakness that, optimum comfort and function (quality of life) (Worldbank website ).In health care market there is a few buyers and sellers instability of information therefrom intrusion of consumer sovereignty allocation of resources by physicians and not price mechanism etc. Therefore patients face a dilemma in translating their desire for good health into a quest for checkup care. This requires both information and aesculapian knowledge, which they usually do not buy off off. There is no definitive and widely needed definition of SID. In literature, the definitions range from positive and value dispatch (Fuchs 1978) to normative with negative connotations (Folland et al 2001, p. 04). McGuire (2000, p504) says that SID exists when the physician influences a patients train for care against the physicians interpretation of the best interest of the patient. Labelle et al (1994, p. 363) point out the need to incorporate in the definition of SID both the effectiveness of the federal performance relationship and the effectiveness of the induced run. This means that inducement can ante up rise to good or bad outcomes for patients depending on its clinical effectiveness, e. g. f a heal persuades a patient to undertake more treatment where the patient would otherwise acquit opted for a less than clinically effective package of care. Rationale for the existence of SID The theoretical analysis of SID is based upon the assumption that doctors maximise their profit publication to income and inducement. Dranove (1988, p 281) argues that under certain conditions the physician will have an motivator to recommend treatments whose costs outweigh their aesculapian benefits. SID involves a supplanting of the indigence curve, such that as proviso ncreases, essential too add-ons (Fig. 1). In rule the exact hold curves themselves cannot be measured. Only the equilibrium points (A, B, C and D) of the overall market can be observed. If the write out of doctors summations from Q1 to Q2 (Fig. 1a), then the tap account payable dec reases from P1 to P2. But if SID exists (Fig. 1b), as the consequence of doctors increases from Q1 to Q2 the doctor would keep shifting the engage curve from D through to D3 in order to maintain or increase income. Fig. 1 Graphical representation of competing hypothesesThe capableness for SID to arise is molded but not guaranteed by a number of characteristics of the health care market including information gaps and asymmetries which encourage patients to seek medical advice and delegate decision-making to doctors potential weaknesses in the agency relationship and the impact of clinical uncertainty on the decision making processes of doctors. Systems for financing, organising and paying for medical services also influence doctor and patient deportment.The asymmetry of information between user and provider is the most fundamental peculiarity of health care, and the source of the most severe losers of market processes during resource allocation. Informational asymmetries may also invalidate the assumption of consumer sovereignty which underlies evaluative polity assessment in much of economics. Patients will a great deal be relatively poorly informed compared with their doctor about their condition, treatment options, expected outcomes and likely costs. Unlike other professional services, information asymmetry is most pronounced in health care markets.Many researchers have tested the hypothesis that more knowledgeable patients should be resistant to SID and that they should therefore make less use of medical care. Surprisingly these studies have consistently arrange that knowledgeable patients frequently use more care Bunker and brownness (1974) Hay and Leahy (1982) and Kenkel (1990). The institutional responses to information asymmetry are professionalisation, self-regulation, and the development of an agency relation between individual transactors and between the professions and society collectively.Agency relationship is formed whenever a princip al (patient) delegates decision-making authority to some other party, the agent (doctor). Ill-informed consumers are protected, by provider advice, from usance of unnecessary or harmful services (inappropriate or poor quality) and also from failure to consume needed services. If this agency relationship were perfect, doctor would take on entirely the patients point of view and act as if he/she were the patient. All consumption choices made for the patient by the provider would be made so as to maximize the patients (and ultimately societys) profit function. health care providers do not always act as perfect agents for their patients. Their recommendations are sometimes influenced by expedience, or the interest of the nerve for which they work. This imperfect agency arises because the doctor (agent) performs a dual role the resembling person who provides advice about a treatment usually provides and receives payment for that treatment. Hence, postulate is no longer self-suff icient of supply the agent can shift the demand curve to any position (Fig. 1b).The demand curve (Figure 1a), assumes that independent consumers of care are not directly influenced by suppliers in their decisions to use care, or alternatively that if such direct influence exists, its level is heady external to the market process itself. On the other hand, it has been shown that in pique of the presumed physician influence over the patient, the physician cannot predict the level of patient compliance (Goldberg et al 1998). Therefore it is doubtful how much influence the physician wields over the patient when it comes to SID.Traditionally doctors behaviour is controlled by a professional code- Hippocratic oath. Financial opportunism on the part of the physicians is only one of the causes of imperfect agency. Another very important cause is the failure of physicians to understand or accept patients preferences regarding the impact of health status on utility and provide this informa tion to the patient (Labelle et al 1994). The steer income possibility posits that as the number of physicians has increased, they have induced additional demand to get a particular income, e. g. y change magnitude the volume and variety of tests and procedures. This is in contrast with conventional economics where increasing supply lowers the price for the consumer. The target income is determined by the local income distribution (Rizzo and Blumenthal, 1996). A professional service like health care is inherently heterogeneous and nonretradable. A noncompetitive competitor selling a nonretradable service sets a quantity to maximize profit and unless there is some cost to inducement, a physician or dental practitioner pursuing net income would induce demand to an unnumberable extent (Gaynor 1994).However, physicians prefer not to induce demand and only do so if they are breedd by adequate gains in income. The utility maximisation of physicians is limited by disutility of discr etion, i. e. either the physicians indwelling conscience (Evans 1974 Mcguire and Pauly 1991) or as a result of a composition process by which doctors who excessively induce demand are punished through future reductions in true patient demand (Dranove 1988). SID can arise when clinical uncertainty causes provision of unnecessary or wasteful medical services even if doctors act in the perceived interests of their patients.If a doctor inadvertently underestimates a patients ability to pay for the cost of medical procedures, the level of care recommended might exceed that which the patient would have nominated. However, some analysts maintain that doctors responses to clinical uncertainty can give rise to SID fully consistent with the patients interests rather than self-interest (Richardson and Peacock 1999, p. 9) e. g. use of diagnostics in excess of standard levels in the event of diagnostic uncertainty. Institutional and regulatory arrangements influence how medical markets work.T hey prepare incentives or disincentives for doctors (and patients) to behave in ways that could engender SID. For example, the cost-bearing and financing aspects of the doctors service are largely borne by third parties (i. e. governments and cloistered insurers). As a consequence, typically neither the consumer nor the provider carefully considers the price or cost of the service supplied. This can influence the extent and form of SID. Other arrangements that can promote SID include the system of payment for doctors (i. e. ee-for-service, capitation or salaried) the effect of medical indemnity arrangements on the adoption of defensive medical practices by doctors and the form of monitoring of doctor treatment practices. The link between physicians and pharmaceutical companies can also promote SID. Big pharmaceutical companies draw close physicians and ask them to prescribe specific drugs to patients in exchange for a reward, such as free holidays. For example, in 2002 drug firm s spent nearly $9. 4 billion on marketing to American doctors (The Economist 15th Feb. 2003). As a result, physicians are illing to prescribe extra medicines that are unnecessary and provide no benefit to the patient. Moreover, these drugs favoured by the physicians and produced by big companies might be more expensive than others with equivalent effectiveness However, one major reproval of the SID model is that it focuses on only one price the nominal fee levelwhile ignoring access costs. If increased supply reduces travel time and office waits, the total cost of care has fallen even if fees stay put constant. Secondly, the SID theory carries an implicit assumption that the extra services are unnecessary.An alternative view is that few situations in medicine are clear-cut and a broad range of indications is consistent with generally acceptable practice. Empirical narrate of SID Several indirect hypotheses and empirical tests have been carried out but collectible to the lack of a rigorous theoretical model and the presence of econometric and measurement problems, results concerning the existence of SID still remain controversial and inconclusive. SID is not clean to measure and interpret because of the difficulty of separating out induced from un-induced demand, supply changes from demand changes and SID from other factors influencing demand (e. . income, insurance coverage, health status). However, there is clear separate that physicians who are paid on fee-for-service basis can adjust the number of services in response to limitations on the levels of fees (Rice, 1983), but such responses are not automatic and health economists dont have a good thought of what contextual factors are important in predicting such responses. Nevertheless, the potential for such responses means that inducement is an important factor to consider in policy development. To test for SID early studies disembodied spirited at changes in engagement compared to increases in phys ician/population ratio.The hypothesis underlying the tests is that, in response to an increase in the doctor/population ratio (i. e. competition), doctors will seek to induce demand or raise their fees so as to maintain their incomes. Cromwell and Mitchell (1986) demonstrated a significant demand inducement for surgical procedures with overall rates of military operation increase by about 0. 08% for each 1% increase in surgeon supply. Rices (1984) found that 10% decline in physician reimbursement led to a 6. 1% increase in extravagance of medical services and a 2. 7% increase in flashiness in surgical services.However, a same study found conglomerate responses to fee changes across procedures (Labelle et al 1990). Another technique used for examen SID is to examine the effect of changes in doctor supply on doctor compared with patient initiated visits. Assumption here is that if SID exists, increases in doctor numbers would lead to an increase in doctor-initiated visits (that is, an income maintenance response test). Tussing and Wojtowycz (1986), using this technique, found that areas with more GPs were associated with much larger proportion of return visits arranged by doctor, i. e. a strong relationship to support SID.On the other hand, doing a similar experiment, Rossiter and Wilensky (1983) found only very small inducement effect. This approach to analyse the presence of SID effects (increasing physicians and increasing utilisation) fell somewhat out of favour when Dranove and Wehner (1994) found that, according to the standard methodology among SID theorists, an increase in the number of physicians resulted in an increase in childbirths. Recent studies have looked at physician behaviour in response to fee reduction, e. g. Yip (1998) found that physicians compensate for income losses due to public price reduction by increasing volume.Medicare fee cuts lead to increased amounts of heart surgery enabling physicians to compensate 70% of lost revenue. Gruber and Owings (1996) found that a 13% reduction in fertility rate in the US in 1970-1982 led to an increase in caesarean sections and reduction in the less profitable vaginal births. Between 1971-1981, the number of GPs per capita in Winnipeg, Canada increased by 56%. Remarkably, however, square gross income per physician remained virtually unchanged during the period. GPs simply increased the number of contacts with existing patients so much so that their average revenue in reality increased (Roch et al 1985).On the other hand, in Norway, Grytten and Sorensen (2001) compared a salaried group of physicians with another one that was compensated by fee for service. neither of the two groups of physicians increased their output as a response to an increase in physician density. In UK, dentists are paid on a fixed fee-for-service basis. Supplier income can only be increased by increasing utilisation. Therefore, testing for the existence of SID in dentistry has involved sounding for a positive correlation between dentist density and utilisation of dental care.Birch (1988) concluded that a positive correlation between the number of dentists per capita and the treatment content per visit provides sufficient (but not necessary) usher for the existence of SID, in a fee-regulated market environment. Other researchers Manning and Phelps (1979) Grytten et al (1990)found similar correlations. Sintonen and Maljanen (1995) found that individual and general inducement appeared to have considerable effect on utilisation, but no systematic connection with supply conditions (dentist/population ratio).This was interpreted to indicate that some dentists, regardless of the market situation, have adopted individual inducement. However, there are alternative explanations for a positive correlation between dentist density and the utilisation of medical services permanent access demand on the market for medical services due to price regulation demand decisions by rational pati ents (the disruption of new practices, particularly in rustic areas, reduces the average time and maneuver costs, and the average time spent in the waiting room also falls) reversed causality where physicians set up shop in naughty demand regions (Zweifel 1981 p216).Policy Implications of SID SID is of great importance to the policy maker because it threatens the grassroots market paradigm and severely undermines economic recommendations about market policy. There are differing interpretations of policy significance of SID. According to Carlsen and Grytten (2000), policy makers can lick the socially optimal density of physicians without knowledge of SID. Yet most analysts look at SID from the perspective of manpower and reimbursement policy for purposes of cost containment. They do not consider its contribution to the health status of patients.The impact of SID on equity, distributional issues and the net social benefits is usually ignored (Labelle et al 1994). The issue of SID raises another major controversy of whether adequate control over resource allocation to and within healthcare is best achieved through the demand side or through regulatory controls on the supply side (Reinhardt 1989, p. 339). Indeed, due to problems with incorrupt hazard and SID, insurers use demand-side incentives (e. g. co-insurance and deductibles), as well as supply-side incentives aimed at providers (e. g. aying physicians through salary or capitation). An example of policy implications of SID to manpower planning is when a government wishes to attract physicians to rural areas, and it does so by paying rural doctors more than those in urban areas. This could precipitate SID within urban practices, so nullifying the governments intention. Direct regulation of the supply of physiciansby mandating that all new graduates spend a certain number of years in rural communities, for example might have some advantages, although this may well affect the number and quality of medical students.For facility planning purposes, Roemers Law has the fundamental implication that there is no external demand standard, based on observed utilisation, from which needed levels can be inferred. Providers will themselves determine use on the basis of available capacity inter alia. SID means increased demand by patients, which raises costs of care. If it exists, then the policy maker may wish to provide for control of supplier behaviour by mandating evidence-based medicine cost-effectiveness evaluation of new interventions, medical audits etc, all of which impinge on clinical freedom.Use of provider payment mechanisms like salaries for doctors, inter field of study budgets, and teddy payments could help. However, Ferguson (2002) argues that overall, demand curve for medical care slopes downward, and that supplier-induced demand is overrated as a policy concern. Conclusion This essay has explained the rationale for the existence of SID and has explored its policy implication s and empirical evidence of its existence. There is arguably sufficient evidence to accept that SID can occur. Even Hippocrates himself realised that as in all things free-lance(a) (in health care it is fee-for-service) there is no such thing as pure altruism.Indeed, the Hippocratic oath is an admission to the potential for pecuniary self-interest and abuse of sacred trust. Imperfect agency and clinical uncertainty are the main causes of SID. If SID is pervasive, there could be a variety of economy-wide impacts, e. g. it could increase health expenditure without a commensurate improvement in health outcomes. Therefore, it has important implications for the health policy process. Strong support for SID hypothesis was found in the UK dentistry. Otherwise, there is no robust evidence on the likely magnitude of SID.Although inconclusive, most studies suggest that where SID arises, it is small both in absolute terms and relative to other influences. However, it is still worth considerin g SID-attenuating arrangements say in the case of physician reimbursement policy. As there are a number of fundamental and seemingly irresolvable methodological and data problems associated with trying to assess SID, definitive evidence of its existence most likely will remain illusive. References 1. Arrow, K. J. (1963). Uncertainty and the social welfare economics of health check Care.American stinting Review 53 941-973. 2. Birch, S. (1988). The acknowledgment of supplier-inducement in a fixed price system of health care provision The case of dentistry in the United Kingdom. Journal of health political economy. 7129150. 3. Bunker, J. P. and Brown, B. W. (1974). The physician patient as an informed consumer of surgical services. clean England Journal of Medicine 290 1051-1055 4. Carlsen, F. and Grytten, J. (2000). Consumer satisfaction and supplier induced demand. Journal of Health Economics 19731-753 5. Cromwell, J. and Mitchell J. (1986). physician-Induced get hold of for S urgery. Journal of Health Economics 5 293-313. 6. Doessel, D. P. (1995). Commentary. In Harris, A. (ed), Economics and Health 1994, Proceedings of the Sixteenth Australian assemblage of Health Economists, School of Health Services Management, University of New South Wales, NSW. 7. Dranove, D. (1988). Demand inducement and the physician/patient relationship. Economic Inquiry 26281-298 8. Dranove, D. and P. Wehner (1994) doc-induced demand for childbirths Journal of Health Economics 1361-73 9. Evans, R. G. (1974).Supplier induced demand some empirical evidence & implications. In Perlman, M. (ed). The economics of health & medical care. London Macmillan 10. Ferguson, B. S. (2002). Issues in the demand for medical care can consumers and doctors be trusted to make the right choices? AIMS Health Care Reform scope Paper 5. Halifax AIMS http//www. aims. ca/Publications/Demand/demand. pdf (accessed 26th April 2004). 11. Folland, S. , Goodman, A. and Stano, M. (2001). The Economics of Healt h and Health Care. 3rd ed, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey. Prentice Hall 12. Fuchs, V. (1978).The supply of surgeons and the demand for operations. Journal of Human Resources, 13(supplement) 3556. 13. Gaynor, M. (1994). Issues in the Industrial presidential term of the Market for mendelevium Services. The Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 3(1) 211-255. 14. Goldberg, A. I. Cohen, G. and Rubin, A-H E. (1998). Physician Assessments of Patient Compliance with medical examination Treatment. Social Science and Medicine 47(11) 1873-6) 15. Gruber, J. and Owings, M. (1996). Physician financial incentives and caesarean section delivery, RAND Journal of Economics 27(1) 99-123. 6. Grytten, J. and Sorensen, R. (2001). Type of exhort and supplier-induced demand for primary physicians in Norway. Journal of Health Economics 20 379-393. 17. Grytten, J. , Holst, D. and Laakf, P. (1990). Supplier Inducement Its Effect on dental consonant Services in Norway Journal of Health Economics 9 483-491 18. Hay, J. and Leahy, M. (1982) Physician-induced demand An empirical analysis of the consumer information gap. Journal of Health Economics 1 231-244. 19. Kenkel, D. (1990) Consumer health information and the demand for medical care.Review of Economics and Statistics 52 587-595 20. Labelle, R. , Hurley, J. and Rice, T. (1990). Financial Incentives and Medical Practice Evidence from Ontario on the Effect of Changes in Physician tiptoes on Medical Care Utilisation, Working Paper 90-4 Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis, MacMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario 21. Labelle, R. , Stoddart, G. and Rice, T. (1994), A Re-examination of the Meaning and magnificence of Supplier-Induced Demand. Journal of Health Economics 13(3) 347-368. 22. Manning, W. G. , Jr. and Phelps, C. E. (1979). The demand for dental care.Bell Journal of Economics 10(2) 503525. 23. McGuire, T. (2000 chapter 9). Physician agency. In Culyer, A. J. and Newhouse, J. P. (eds). Handbook of Health Econo mics, 1A, Elsevier North Holland. 24. McGuire, T. G. , and Pauly, M. V. (1991). Physician Response to Fee Changes with Multiple Payers. Journal of Health Economics 10 385-410. 25. Reinhardt, U. (1989). Economists in health care saviours, or elephants in a porcelain shop? American Economic Review 79 337-342. 26. Rice, T. (1983). The Impact of Changing Medicare Reimbursement Rates on Physician-induced Demand.Medical Care. 21(8) 803-815. 27. Rice, T. (1984). Physician-induced demand New evidence from the Medicare program. Advances in Health Economics and Health Services look into 6129-160 28. Richardson, J. and Peacock, S. (1999). Supplier-induced demand reconsidered. Working Paper 81, CHPE, Monash University. http//chpe. buseco. monash. edu. au/pubs/wp81. pdf (accessed twenty-seventh April 2004). 29. Rizzo, J. A. and Blumenthal, D. A. (1996). Is the Target-Income Hypothesis an Economic Heresy? Medical Care Research and Review 53(3) 243266. 30. Roch, D. Evans, R. G. and Pascoe, D. (19 85). Manitoba and Medicare 1971 to Present. Winnipeg, Manitoba Manitoba Health. 31. Roemer, M. I. (1961). Bed supply and hospital utilisation A national experiment, Hospitals. Journal of American Health Affairs 35988993 32. Rossiter, L. and Wilensky, G. , (1983). The Relative Importance of Physician-Induced Demand for Medical Care. Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly 61(2) 252-277. 33. Sintonen, H. and Maljanen, T. (1995). Explaining the Utilisation of Dental Care Experiences from the Finnish Dental Market.Health Economics 4(6) 453-466. 34. Tussing, A. D. and Wojtowycz, M. (1986). Physician-induced Demand by Irish General Practitioners. Economic and Social Review 14(3) 225-247 35. Worldbank website http//www1. worldbank. org/hnp/hsd/HEGlossary. asp (accessed 27th April 2004). 36. Yip, W. (1998). Physician Responses to Medical Fee Reductions Changes in the Volume and Intensity of submit of Coronary, Artery Bypass Graft (CABG) Surgeries in the Medicare and Private Sectors, Journal of Hea lth Economics 17(6) 675-699 37.Zweifel, P. (1981 p245-267). Supplier Induced Demand in a regulate of Physician Behaviour. In van der Gaag, J. and Perlman, M. (eds), Health, Economics and Health Economics. Amsterdam North-Holland P- fees for ServiceQ- supply of doctors S- supply curve of servicesD- demand curve for services P2 P1 Q1 Q2 D C A S1 S P3 P1 P2 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 D D2 D1 D3 S1 S B (a) No SID(b) With SID D

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.